AGRICULTURAL AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT POLICIES
BETWEEN MARKET ORIENTATION AND PROTECTIONISM IN CEECs
Dr. Janos V. Budavari
International Economist
Food and Agriculture organization of the United Nations
Rome, Italy
INTRODUCTION
The trade policy aspect of developing successful agricultural
and rural development policies has always been in the limelight
of interest in Europe. It has acquired a new accent by the Uruguay
Round Agreement on Agriculture (URAA) which saw the start of its
implementation at mid-1995. The increased interest is due to the
fact that several provisions of the URAA aim at directly influencing
national agricultural policies from the point of view of creating
more liberal conditions for international trade in agricultural
and food products.
In general terms, nations find it beneficial to participate in
international agricultural trade due to the great diversity of
production conditions among regions, because of decreasing costs
of production of some food products and also due to differences
in taste. The ultimate argument for trade in agriculture and processed
food products, however, is the desire to benefit from national
comparative advantages.
For that reason, many economists tend to have a great preference
for free trade and even for completely liberalized trading conditions
also in agriculture. On the other hand, they incline to condemn
any measure aiming at import protection. They also have a strong
dislike of all kinds of government intervention in domestic agricultural
markets.
The present brief essay undertakes to contribute to those efforts
aiming at a more differentiated approach to this controversial
issue in the case of Central and Eastern European Countries (CEECs).
The main objective of such an approach is supposed to be striking
a balance between the necessity of market orientation in eastern
agri-food sectors and targeted policies aiming at a limited market
protection.
Recent, in part negative, practical experience stimulates us to
do so and, in fact, policy makers in CEECs are searching for such
a balance. Such a dynamic balance is supposed to be the function
of the specific nature of agricultural markets, on the one hand,
and of specific national characteristics and situations, on the
other. Above all, it should more and more reflect the emerging
new multifunctional role of European agricultural and rural areas
and their population.
ACTIVE MARKET POLICIES REQUIRED
Within a market based international economy, markets for non-agricultural
products and markets for agricultural commodities have many common
principles whereas they show also important differences. Common
to both is the crucial regulating role of prices. They are the
most important indicators for managerial decisions about supply
and investments as well as for decisions about consumption. At
the same time, they are also the result of the complex interaction
of supply and demand (and also of some other factors).
One basic difference in the behavior of different commodity markets
is the great instability inherent to international markets for
agricultural products. This manifests itself in great price fluctuations
due to the specific characteristics of agricultural commodities.
Some of their specific features are: inelastic supply and demand;
strong short term changes in supply due to unforeseeable events;
production and price cycles; as well as great quantities of subsidized
exports from traditional market economies.
Experience has shown that such price fluctuations may have extremely
negative impacts on the income development and social situations
in the national rural sectors. The more open the country's economy
is, the stronger the negative impact may be, in particular, when
a given sub-sector's market power is very little vis-a-vis its
mighty international competitors. It is a fact that presently,
most transition countries of CEE fall in this category.
Another persisting source of market instability in CEECs is the
great discrepancy in economic potential and bargaining power between
producers of the primary sector and the subsequent processing
and marketing stages. The legal dissolution and/or sale of monopolies
downstream (and upstream) have not eliminated at once the economic
base for their existence. Even if partly decentralized and privatized,
processing plants, retail trade enterprises and foreign trade
companies are continuing to capitalise on their earlier territorial
position, business contacts and expertise. Producers, especially
the emerging group of new private farmers have no possibility
to influence prices and to defend themselves against strong market
fluctuations.
One serious negative consequence of "imported" and "home-made"
instability of the domestic agricultural market is discouraging
agricultural investments. This is affecting the long-term position
and economic existence of the agricultural sector with the possible
final effect of socially destabilizing parts of rural regions.
Apart from other factors (like the uncertainties connected with
the restructuring process), the lack of market stability entailed
a serious reduction of agricultural investments in the CEECs during
the nineties.
During the past decade, in fact, parallel to the Uruguay Round
negotiations the awareness grew in Europe that beyond their economic
function (i.e. food production) agricultural and rural areas also
perform valuable ecological and socio-cultural functions for the
society as a whole. These functions seem to increase in importance
in western European and also in some CEECs. For those functions
to be performed, however, the stability and gradual evolution
of rural structures in their widest sense is absolutely necessary.
This is true even if the ecological and socio-cultural services
rendered by the rural population are to be preferably paid for
by direct payments (within the obvious financial limits) and not
by continuing price subsidization.
Abrupt out-migration from the rural sector as a result of strong
market fluctuations is not desirable at the present stage of economic
transition in eastern European countries. In fact, the rural sector
has been playing a useful bumper role in the labor market by absorbing
part of the unskilled labor set free by urban employers in most
CEE countries during the early nineties.
The above reasons clearly call for and justify active market policies
to be pursued by CEE governments including targeted market intervention
and qualified import protection in order to create a minimum stability
on the domestic agricultural market. It is obvious that this should
occur within the framework set by the multilateral trade agreements.
Moreover, the above reasoning also seems to explain the course
of agricultural policies pursued by CEECs during the early nineties.
In that period, the initial rapid trade liberalization was first
followed by ad-hoc measures of market intervention and import
protection. Then, the individual measures gradually developed
into a more or less consolidated package of policy measures and
instruments in several CEECs.
It is hardly deniable that without a reasonable minimum of market
stability, no sound structural policy can be pursued in order
to overhaul the obsolete agricultural and rural structures in
transition countries. However, it is the modernization of those
structures which forms the key precondition for improved competitiveness
and better living conditions in the agricultural and rural sector.
THE COUNTERPART: ACTIVE STRUCTURAL POLICIES
What has been briefly referred to in the previous section, i.e.
CEECs do have to pursue an active market policy, is only one side
of the same policy issue: designing balanced agricultural and
rural development policies for the specific needs of countries
in transition in CEE. Namely, the necessary counterpart of market
regulation policies must preferably be an active structural policy
aiming at the modernization of agrarian structures (including
ownership and farm structure; rural infrastructure; output patterns
of agriculture and forestry; overall economic structure of rural
areas; rural occupational structure, etc).
It has to be pointed out right from the beginning that the use
of scarce budgetary resources for price guarantees and export
subsidies is only rational if they help to introduce some structural
development measures aiming at the improved viability of a certain
sub-sector. Likewise, the use of import protection measures is
only justifiable if simultaneous efforts are undertaken to improve
the international competitiveness of the protected sub-sector
and its products. Furthermore, the horizon of structural measures
has to reach beyond the boundaries of agricultural production.
They have to address the whole economic, social and ecological
complex of rural areas with an eye on the criteria of sustainable
development.
According to general policy experience, today's structural health
of a given agricultural sub-sector and its economic environment
decides about its success or failure in the medium to long term.
Therefore, it seems to be essential that a major share of the
tight agricultural budget and international financial assistance
be devoted to structural and human resources development and not
to market support programs. If actions of market policy and structural
policy are not simultaneously and consistently adopted, funds
spent on market support may result in the contrary of what they
were meant for. They will entail misallocation of resources, decrease
of competitiveness, higher food consumer prices, more political
pressure for more subsidies, overstrained agricultural budget,
etc.
Consequently, market protection and import protection measures introduced for minimum market stability should not be generalized and should not be continuing long-term. In order to be effective, they should be:
The CEECs have already set, no doubt, an impressive record of market oriented agricultural restructuring by the mid-nineties. They stand now at very different stages of the overall transition process. For long-term development, active structural policies should focus above all on international competitiveness rather than on output growth. This seems to be valid particularly for CEECs with the most open economies. Improving competitiveness will be important even for preserving a reasonable share of the domestic market for the sake of national food security. Furthermore, structural policies have to reflect the fact that by the nineties the meaning and content of comparative advantages in the agri-food sector have significantly changed. They do not mainly rely on good physical conditions and producer traditions any more.
Improving competitiveness of products and services lies primarily in the responsibility of farming, processing, marketing and trade enterprises. Governments, apart from creating a stable macroeconomic environment as the most fundamental prerequisite, have to facilitate this process by specific structural policies. At the present stage of the agricultural transition process, the following priorities for structural measures seem to be of particular relevance:
The foregoing list of priorities for structural policies would,
of course, need further refinement for the purposes of any one
transition country, however, it covers the main issues deserving
special attention presently. Meeting these and other priorities
by market-oriented adjustments, however, will presumably require
a substantial amount of time in most CEECs.
CONCLUSIONS
Under conditions of a market oriented transformation process in
the agri-food sectors of CEECs, instability of domestic agricultural
markets due to fluctuations in the international markets could
submit agricultural and rural regions to extreme economic and
social strains. This could lead to a destabilization of rural
regions or even to a quasi collapse of national food systems.
During the period of intensive structural adjustments, a minimum of market stability is therefore essential. This justifies active market policies on the part of governments including targeted market intervention and qualified import protection measures. The free trade concept, as theoretically being the best for resource utilization and economic development should not become an exclusive trade ideology or even a dogma to be applied indiscriminately throughout the eastern European agriculture. Like its western European
counterpart, also CEE agriculture is developing towards a multifunctional
type of agriculture. It also performs important socio-cultural
(and hopefully later ecological) functions which are worth to
be preserved in the long-run.
It is essential for the CEECs that the two principal groups of agricultural policy mechanisms, i.e. market policies and structural policies follow harmonized objectives and be complementary. Both types of policies have to be active simultaneously and consistently. By ensuring this, provisional market protection may create the sufficient time for structural measures to be active. The latter, on their turn, may reduce the necessity of providing renewed market protection in the future.