IMPLICATIONS OF POSSIBLE CHANGES IN THE EU

COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY FOR THE AGRI-FOOD SECTOR

IN CENTRAL EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

Antonio MD Nucifora

Queen Elizabeth House

University of Oxford

United Kingdom


ABSTRACT

The study looks at the impact of possible strategies for EU agricultural policy change on CEECs in the light of the accession of these countries to the European Union. Different strategies are evaluated using a simple static partial equilibrium model. The model provides us with an estimate of the economic costs and benefits of the alternative policy options; these results are then discussed taking into account the specific problems of the agri-food sector in CEE countries. The results of the study underline the advantages of a reform involving the removal of production related support in the EU, cushioned by temporary, digressive fully decoupled compensation and slowly replaced by complementary environmental and socio-structural policies. This would remove the serious distortions in EU agriculture and allow environmental, social and regional objectives to be addressed in a more targeted way. For the Central and East European countries such a reform would ease the path to accession and foster the development of a dynamic agri-food sector by allowing funds to be re-directed for modernization and restructuring.


1. Introduction

Potentially the most important aspect of their accession to the European Union for the Central and Eastern European countries (CEECs) is the set of agricultural policies which they would adopt as a result of EU membership. This is both because of the key importance of the agriculture in these countries (Anderson and Tyers 1993a; Tyers 1994) and because of the particular prominence of agricultural policies in the European Union. In the EU, however, the need for further agricultural policy reforms has recently begun to be discussed. Clearly, a different set of agricultural policies would have different implications for the CEECs economies. In particular, the costs of adopting the present CAP have already been indicated by several studies (Buckwell et al. 1995, Tangermann et al. 1995, Tarditi et al. 1995). More recently, the Commission has indicated in its White Paper on accession its own favoured strategy for agricultural reform in view of the Eastern enlargement (Commission 1995). However, most studies have focused on analyzing the impact of such policy changes on the EU, and no analysis of the implications of different policies for the CEECs economies has been presented. This paper intends to provide an initial attempt to consider and quantify the economic costs and benefits of such different policies for the CEECs by using a simple static partial equilibrium model. Its intention is to underline the implications of different policies for the downstream and upstream sectors, as well as for the wider economy, of these countries.

In section 2 the Commission's White Paper on integrating the CEECs is discussed briefly; in section 3 the policy options available for the future are discussed; in section 4 the model is introduced and in section 5 there is a discussion of the results.

2. The Commission's White Paper on integrating the

CEECs into the CAP

In the white paper on integrating the CEECs into the CAP presented in December 1995, the Commission makes explicit what it sees as the best strategy for CEECs accession to the EU. After highlighting the need for change in European agricultural policies the Commission's White Paper goes on to illustrate the different possible strategies and concludes that "among the different possible options, the Commission clearly favours developing the approach that was started successfully with the 1992 reform. This implies a reduced reliance on price support, compensated where necessary by direct payments, whatever their concrete form may be. Furthermore, it implies a better integration between market policies, rural development and environmental policies".

The strategy paper also calls for a special fund to be set up to help the CEECs prepare for EU membership through infrastructure improvement and sector restructuring. It is recognized in the Paper that, although farm policy is an important element in the decision over accession of the CEECs, structural policy is the key issue. CEE countries are recognized to be less in need of a high level of price and income support, than of targeted assistance for restructuring, modernization and diversification in agriculture and in the downstream sectors.

However, although the notion that extending the current CAP is neither feasible nor desirable and that structural policy is the key issue for CEECs' agricultural sectors seems to have been accepted by the Commission, no clear strategy has been indicated and no commitments have been made to facilitate the development of a healthy and dynamic agricultural sector in the CEECs.

For instance, the Paper does not explain how its new approach for an "integrated rural policy" would be funded, although it suggests the need for additional finance. Also, the inappropriateness of extending agricultural production quotas to the expanding CEECs is not considered. Furthermore, no detailed discussion of the issue of compensatory payments for set-aside and price cuts is presented, in spite of the fact that they too represent an obstacle to enlargement. In the Paper we only find a firm rejection of the idea of phasing out market support and bringing in decoupled and digressive direct income payments on the grounds that this "radical" type of reform, though "appealing from an economist's point of view", would entail high "social and environmental risks". Finally, although the need for an explicit an active structural policy in favour of the CEECs agricultural and processing industries is recognized, no explicit funding policies are identified.

It is, therefore, unclear how the Commission intends to go about extending the CAP to CEE countries and this is highlighted by the vague and at least partially inconsistent nature of current proposals; one can predict that this will translate into an attempt to accommodate the new entrants within the existing framework, in spite of its well known deficiencies and of its inappropriateness for the economies in transition.

3. Agricultural policy options for the European Union

From the brief discussion of the previous section it appears that the policy options open to the EU lie between the three following possibilities: a persistence of the 'Status Quo' situation, a minimal reform of the CAP following the lines of the White Paper, and a more comprehensive reform of the CAP. We now move on to discuss in more detail the characteristics of each of these three options.

3.1 Option A: Maintaining the "Status Quo"

This involves an attempt to extend the CAP as it is to the CEE countries. The "Status Quo" option sees the Commission, who will no doubt encounter strong pressure from farm lobbies, play down the importance of the warnings of the need for change and continue the process of slowly extending, in as far as is necessary (mainly because of international GATT/WTO obligation), the present CAP to other major commodities.

The problems with this approach are well known and several have been emphasized in the White Paper itself. Firstly, the MacSharry reforms have not solved the budgetary problems of the CAP; total expenditure has had to increase in real terms as the burden previously borne by consumers has moved onto the government; on top of this, farmers have been overcompensated for price cuts. From several studies it appears that the budget costs of extending the present CAP to the CEE countries would be too cumbersome for the EU budget, considerably exceeding the financial guideline.

Secondly, there is the issue of compensatory payments. Extending these compensations to the CEE countries is just as unfeasible, from a financial point of view, as is extending the current levels of price support. On the other hand, although the compensatory payments to EU farmers are to some extent decoupled from production (Josling 1993, p.98), they are not fully decoupled. Therefore, compensatory payments either will have to be entirely decoupled from the production process, so that they can be maintained for EU farmers only, or else they will have to be (considerably) reduced in size so as to allow their extension to CEECs farmers as well. Here we implicitly adopt the former solution on the grounds that it would not be politically easy to reduce these payments in order to share them with East-European farmers; however, the solution to decouple payments fully in order to keep them exclusively for EU-15 farmers (on the grounds that CEECs' farmers are not suffering a reduction in prices so that they need not to be compensated) opens serious equity issues and cannot be considered as permanent.

A further problem with the present CAP is that the policy of setting aside land (which is needed in the EU because compensatory payments are not fully decoupled), has strong negative implications for land use; for instance, in 1993 it consigned around 12% (3.7 out of 30.4 mio hectares in EU-12 in 1993) of land previously used for cereal production to forced inactivity. In other words, such a policy recognizes the existence of a land surplus under cereal production, but does not encourage a better allocation, freezing the status quo rather than fostering change. Such a policy cannot, however, be pursued indefinitely. The results of a recent study suggest that by 2010 there will be up to 5.4 mio hectares of land surplus to agricultural production in EU-9 only (Nucifora 1995a, p. 247), without accounting for the area which is already effectively in surplus (Buckwell 1986, p. 9; Wibberley 1983, pp. 17-34).

Clearly, the above issues render the current CAP policy unsustainable in the long run as a means to preserve farmers' incomes while leaving markets undistorted. In fact, as yields continue to increase and the price of agricultural products continues to decline, it will become increasingly unacceptable to set more and more land aside and to compensate farmers for further price cuts in order to preserve their income; such a policy would soon become overwhelmingly costly in budgetary, efficiency and environmental terms, even leaving aside the issue of CEECs accession.

Further, extending the present CAP to CEE countries would raise more immediate problems with the current GATT/WTO constraints agreed by these countries; in fact, many CEE countries would exceed both their AMS and subsidized export constraints if they adopted a CAP-like type of policy; the latter holds especially for the Czech and Slovak Republics and for Hungary who have set their GATT constraints in national currencies (OECD 1995).

In practice, extending the "Status Quo" CAP would soon turn out to be "an impasse" (Commission 1995). However, this option offers the advantage to avoid political turmoil, and arguably, it avoids a high level of social and environmental disruption. Therefore, it is quite possible that the council of agricultural ministers will attempt to ignore these issues, introducing only minimal adjustments to the CAP as they become strictly unavoidable to meet international or budgetary limitations.

In our model we introduced the following policy changes for this option (as discussed later, the model focuses on cereals, beef and dairies only):

a) there is no change in commodity cereal and beef prices in the EU; the same level of support prices is extended to the CEECs;

b) the extension of milk quotas to CEE countries, with quotas for these countries set at 1989 output levels;

c) the continuation of decoupled compensation payments in the EU to compensate for price cuts; though these are not applied to CEECs;

d) the extension of other types of non-price-related support to the level provided to EU farmers for all new CEEC members.

3.2 Option B: Progressively extending the MacSharry

Reform - "White Paper scenario"

Under this "minimal reform-White Paper" scenario, the Commission would again play down the need for long term reform, partly giving in to the pressure exercised by the agricultural producers' lobbies. The Commission would, however, attempt to move in the direction of the White Paper by extending in as far as is possible the reform of the CAP to all other major commodities, with set-aside and reductions in price support and compensating farmers for the loss of income.

The CEECs policy makers would therefore have to refer to a set of policies only partially different from the present ones, in spite of the fact that these have been classified as "RED BOX" or "non-exempt from reduction commitments" in the recent GATT treaty. Policies would include prices close to (ultimately reaching) world price levels for most products, a system of production quotas for milk and sugar, and all other standard CAP product-specific policies.

In particular, we introduced the following policy changes in our model:

a) a reduction in commodity cereal and beef prices to world price levels in both the EU and the CEECs;

b) the extension of milk quotas to CEE Countries, with quotas for these countries set at 1989 output levels;

c) the continuation of decoupled compensation payments in the EU to compensate for price cuts; though these are not applied to CEECs;

d) the extension of other types of non-price-related support to the level provided to EU farmers for all new CEE members.

This reform option would offer the advantage to decrease price support levels, to avoid overwhelming political resistance in the EU and, arguably, to avoid the "social and environmental risks" discussed in the White Paper; however, it also does not deal with some of the issues left open in the White Paper such as the appropriateness of extending production quotas to CEE countries and the problem of compensatory payments. Production quotas have given rise to a rigid and unfair system in the EU and they are all the more inappropriate for the CEECs which are by definition in a state of transition and which are supposed to be developing their comparative advantage in agriculture.

Further, these policies also fail to address the specific need for structural adjustment and modernization of CEECs' agricultural sectors. The present structural problems in the CEECs will prevent these countries from flooding the EU with agricultural products for at least several years; problems persist with unresolved land ownership issues, use of low quality inputs (notably seeds) and inefficiencies in the downstream sectors. As a result, in recent years the agro-food balance has been developing in favour of the EU moving from a deficit in 1992 to an increasing surplus in 1993-94; this is in spite of the fact that all countries operating under association agreements increased their exports to the EU in 1994.

The rate of structural reform will depend, however, on the extent of privatization and on the emergence of functioning land markets, which so far have been hindered by the delay in most countries of the definitive settlement of property rights. A return to profitability of farming does to a large extent also depend on a competitive downstream sector, as well as on a reorganization of the farm sector itself. The EU should, therefore, aim at helping the CEECs to complete land privatization and to build up food processing and marketing.

3.3 Option C: Completing the reform - "Comprehensive

Reform scenario"

Under the "comprehensive reform" scenario we envisage the solution of the issues left unresolved by the current proposals presented in the White Paper. Again, price support would be progressively reduced to reach world price levels, and EU farmers would receive compensation for such reductions. These compensations would be fully decoupled. Similarly, production quotas for milk and sugar would be scrapped and farmers would receive the relevant decoupled compensation.

However, unlike in option B, these payments to the EU farmers would be progressively phased out. It would be possible to do this following a type of progressive phasing such as that proposed by Tracy (1995) or it would be possible to adopt the bond hypothesis advocated by Tangermann et al. (1990). Clearly, this option would imply a considerable one-off budgetary expenditure, particularly in the case of a once-and-for-all disbursement of compensatory payments to farmers via a system of redeemable bonds.

Money diverted from compensatory payments would eventually be redirected towards GREEN BOX structural measures which are "exempt from the reduction commitments" under the GATT treaty.

Total expenditure on agriculture would not, therefore, be reduced. Its amount would still be dictated by the financial guideline, accounting for the contribution of the new members. All expenditure on agriculture would now be concentrated on structural measures and on measures for a diversified rural development (environment, local crafts, agro-tourism and others) in line with the idea of an "integrated rural policy" presented in the White Paper; decoupled income support would be available to less favourable areas and would take the form of a social payment, rather than being camouflaged as an agricultural policy measure.

Although very appealing from an economist's point of view, and in spite of presenting no reductions in total agricultural expenditure, this option may be considered to be politically untenable. However, it offers the advantage of dealing with all matters left open by the Commission's proposals. It resolves the equity issues associated with compensating EU farmers only. It solves the ridiculous proposal of introducing production quotas in the CEE countries. Finally, it also solves the problem of ensuring adequate financing for a comprehensive well funded program of structural measures.

In the "comprehensive reform" scenario we introduce the following policy changes:

a) a reduction in commodity cereal and beef prices to world price levels in both the EU and the CEECs;

b) the elimination of the milk quotas system in the EU with a reduction in the price of milk to the world level;

c) the ultimate phasing out of decoupled compensation payments in the EU to compensate for price cuts;

d) the introduction of additional expenditure in Green Box structural measures;

e) the extension of other types of non-price-related support to the level provided to EU farmers for all new CEECs members.

4. The Model

The countries analyzed in the model include the four Visegrad countries, namely the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and the Slovak Republic, plus Slovenia. The choice of these countries was somewhat arbitrary in that it was carried out according to the simple criteria that they have the highest income out of all candidates for membership and that their economies have all began to show signs of recovery.

The commodities chosen for analysis in the model are cereals, beef and veal, and milk. These were chosen on the dual grounds that they represent a large share of total agricultural production in all selected CEECs and that they currently enjoy a high level of price support in the EU. Other major CEECs commodities, such as pigmeat, fruit and vegetables and potatoes, were not covered because of the limited extent of CAP intervention on these markets.

The starting point for our analysis are the sets of agricultural policies implemented by the various CEE governments and by the EU in agricultural commodity markets in 1994. Costs and benefits of possible policy changes are confronted with those of present agricultural policies. All costs and benefits are calculated using world prices as reference prices.

The model itself is a simple static partial equilibrium model with three commodities and seven countries or country blocks including the EU-15 and the Rest of the World (RoW). The base year is 1994. Two runs are made for each option scenario. The first run uses 1994 prices; the second run allows for the exceptionally high level of agricultural prices in 1994 and sets initial world prices 20% below 1994 levels. In each scenario the relevant policy changes are introduced and the resulting allocative effects are analyzed. The elasticity parameters have been taken from a study by Tyers (1994).

An arbitrary allowance for the effect of agricultural expenditure on the sector's productivity is built into the model; it is assumed that each 0.1% of GDP spent on agriculture brings about a 1% increase in productivity, rising to 1.5% in the case of structural expenditure in the EU and 2% in the case of structural expenditure in the CEECs. In turn this is fed into the model as an equivalent increase in total agricultural production with respect to the base situation. The model also allows for expenditure on structural policies to reduce the inefficiencies in the downstream sector directly; it is assumed that every 0.1% of GDP spent on structural policies would reduce handling margins by 10% of their initial level. These differences in the effect of structural policies on the efficiency of the agricultural sector in the EU and CEECs aim to take into account the exceptionally high present levels of downstream inefficiencies observed in the CEECs, and account for the fast gains available from structural policies in CEE countries as a result of these inefficiencies.

5. Results and policy implications

Given the above assumptions the model was run to give results for each of the three separate policy scenarios. For each scenario two runs were carried out with world prices at 1994 and at 20% below 1994 to account for the exceptionally high current level of agricultural prices. The results of the model and the implications of each policy option for the CEECs are presented below.

The results of the model under the "Status Quo" scenario (Option A), the "Minimal Reform-White Paper" Scenario (Option B), and the "Comprehensive Reform" Scenario (Option C), are summarized in table 1 below for prices at 1994 and in table 2 below for prices 20% below 1994. Results are discussed in the following sub-sections.

Implications for the level of prices

At present, there exists a wide gap between farm gate prices for agricultural products in the EU and in the CEECs. Looking at 1994 prices one can see that with the exception of wheat in Slovenia and pork in Poland, all price ratios are smaller than 100% (Table 3). More generally CEECs agricultural prices only amount to about 50% of the respective EU price, or even less.

Besides differences in price support, the current price wedge can be attributed to two other factors. Firstly, lower prices can partially be explained by the still considerable differences in product quality and standards between the EU and the CEECs. These differences are larger for milk, beef and other meat products and they are less important for Hungary and Slovenia where quality standards are already relatively high.

Secondly, inefficiencies in the food industry and insufficient or lacking wholesale markets seem to be another reason for lower producer prices. At present, the food industry in most CEE countries is characterized by severe overcapacity, increasing input costs, low labour productivity, outdated processing facilities (except in Hungary where foreign investment has helped the creation of new plants) and a lack of market orientation by the management. This situation underlines the current overall stagnation of these industries and, as a result, a lower demand for home produced agricultural products. In addition to these inefficiencies, the market situation in the food industry and in the distribution systems often tends to be characterized by a situation of near-monopsony, with few buyers who have the power to keep down producers' prices.

In fact, very often producer prices in these countries lie not only below the EU prices but quite frequently below the respective world market prices. This, however, does not imply that agriculture is discriminated against by state intervention. Very often the great inefficiencies that exist in the food industry and the marketing system of these countries result in a doubling of the internal prices on the way to the border (Hartmann 1996; OECD, 1994).

Given the present wedge, an extension of the CAP in its present state to the CEE countries would clearly imply a sharp increase in protection levels in the CEECs. Producer and consumer prices in the CEECs would rise dramatically, reaching over 100% increases for some of the products; this would constitute a sharp rise in producer incentives for most agricultural commodities in the CEECs (except non-ruminant meat products which are less strongly supported in the EU than in the CEECs and other products which are not strongly supported under the CAP). Such a substantial increase in prices received by farmers is bound to have serious implications on the agricultural sector and the wider economy.

However, it follows from the preceding discussion that the impact of such an increase in prices (and thus in production incentives) would be reduced if the CEECs are not successful in increasing the quality of their agricultural products and in reducing the inefficiency of their food industry and wholesale markets. In particular, the CEE countries might suddenly lose their price advantage against western European products, while exposing their weakness in quality standards and their inefficiency in processing and distributing agri-food products to western European competition.

Implications for the level of agricultural output

The model used in this study is not sophisticated enough to give a reliable account of all the factors concerning inefficiencies in the distribution system and in the food industry which might reduce the output response to a price increase. However, the results of the model suggest that the "Status Quo" option will induce only a moderate rise in the supply of the three commodities as a response to the strong increase in prices. The rise in supply is stronger in the case of beef, which is also the most price responsive commodity. For milk and cereals the rise in supply is stronger under the other two options, particularly under option C. Under options B and C, the accession would take place at (near) world price levels, thus avoiding strong price shocks to CEECs' economies. Overall, the model thus confirms that production levels in the CEECs do not respond too well to the rise in prices, partly as a result of the implications for demand, and that they are much more responsive to expenditure on structural policies as is indicated by the results under option C.

Implications for the demand for food

The results of the model also confirm the substantial reduction in demand resulting from the sharp increase in prices under option A. Under Option B the negative impact on milk demand is still quite strong, while demand for wheat rises substantially. Over all, food demand has the best response under option C. In particular, under option C, demand for wheat rises considerably while neither beef nor milk demand decrease substantially; this ensures a more balanced diet for a larger part of the population.

Implications for the trade balance

The agricultural trade balance improves under option A. However, this takes place largely at the expense of domestic demand and only partly as a result of the supply rise. On the other hand, the more modest increase in net exports under option C takes place without the need for export subsidies and without the disruption of domestic demand.

Implications on welfare

As is well known market support policies which directly modify relative market prices, such as the CAP of the EU, alter the mechanisms which regulate the allocation of resources in the economy, and which provide a reference for private investment and a means to evaluating the effectiveness of public expenditure in general. These distortions drain resources out of the non-agricultural sectors in favour of the agricultural sector, and impose additional cost to consumers, not only by raising food prices, but also by inflicting a sub-optimal allocation of resources and demands.

An estimate of the welfare costs of these alternative policy options is provided by the model. Welfare costs generally rise quite considerably for all CEE countries under the "Status Quo" scenario (Option A), while they remain very low under the more comprehensive reform scenario (Option C). Welfare costs under the White Paper scenario (Option B) increase somewhat in between. In terms of GNP these costs range from a minimum of 0.74% of GNP for Slovenia to a maximum of 2.41% of GNP for Poland respectively under option A, and from a minimum 0.15% of GNP for Poland to a maximum of 0.61% of GNP for the Slovak Republic respectively under option C. In the case of Poland, therefore, as high as 2% of GNP can be lost depending on the agricultural policies which will be adopted by the EU in the near future. Overall, for all CEE countries welfare cost are smaller under option C.

For world prices 20% below 1994 levels welfare costs are similarly high. They range from a minimum of 1.1% of GNP for Slovenia to a maximum of 2.4%of GNP for Poland respectively under option A, and from a minimum 0.06% of GNP for Poland to a maximum of 0.56% of GNP for Slovenia respectively under option C.

An examination of the welfare losses as a percentage of total expenditure on agriculture provides a measure of the level of transfer efficiency. Under option A transferring one ECU to farmers costs society between 1.4 to 1.9 ECUs, for the Czech Republic and Slovenia respectively; transferring one ECU to farmers under option B costs society between 1.4 to 1.7 ECUs, respectively; finally, under option C transferring one ECU to farmers costs society between 1.03 to 1.2 ECUs. Transfer efficiency thus improves dramatically across the different scenarios moving from a 150-200% cost of transfers under option A to almost complete efficiency under the comprehensive reform scenario. The results are essentially the same for world prices 20% below 1994 levels.

Implications for input prices

In addition, it should be noted that EU integration will also lead to an increase in input prices, which also lie at present far below the respective EU prices. Thus, only a part of the considerable transfer of economic resources from taxpayers and consumers to farmers actually reaches the farmers hands. A portion of the higher revenues generated by price support policies, would be in part capitalized into higher land values resulting in higher rents which benefit the land owner, who may not work or live on the farm. This problem, however, is more important in western European countries where it is common for farmers not to own the land they cultivate; in the CEECs land reform has generally distributed the land to those who undertake to farm it (Csaki 1994, 1995).

The balance, which is not capitalized into higher land values, would flow to non agricultural firms selling input at artificially induced higher prices. In the case of the CEECs this may be looked upon as an advantage of price support, in that it allows the upstream industries to share the benefits of agricultural support. However, this would also have the effect of allowing such firms to remain less efficient and therefore uncompetitive on the world markets.

Implications for the adjustment of the agricultural sector

Price support would also slow down the process of structural adjustment of the agricultural sector; by allowing many inefficient firms to survive in the sector, price support would obstruct the process of enlargement and consolidation of the most successful farms. Similarly, the increase in land prices associated with capitalized rents from a more profitable agriculture would represent a further barrier to structural adjustment in the agricultural sector; it would slow down the process of buying and selling of land, and the entry and exit of firms/farmers in the agricultural industry. Furthermore, as an addition to the increase in land prices, the introduction of constraints on the use of arable land (set-aside) and on the levels of production (notably for milk and sugar), implies that the present CAP would impose a rigid structure on the CEECs agricultural sector, slowing down change and discouraging structural adjustment. The inappropriateness of such a system to the economies in transition should go without saying.

In addition, the artificial rise in input prices and land rents associated with price support would further render the sector artificially uncompetitive on a world level. Higher farm gate prices would also mean higher input prices for the processing industry which, as discussed, is already in great difficulties. Once again, it appears that price support policies would offset the natural comparative advantage of CEE countries in the agro-food sector.

The other important point to note here regards the reductions in handling margins; given the assumptions discussed above concerning the effects of government expenditure on structural measures, handling margins (and differences in products' quality) diminish only marginally under both the A and B options, whilst they decrease considerably more under option C, where margins begin to approach EU levels. We have seen how this is of particular relevance to CEE countries because of the exceptionally high current levels of inefficiency in their downstream sectors which currently offset their extremely low production costs.

Budgetary costs

The budgetary costs of CEEC-5 accession under the current CAP (no reform) are estimated by the model at 14.8 bio ECU. Budgetary costs of accession under option B (minimal reform) are 9.6 bio ECU and rise to 17.1 bio ECU under option C, reflecting the reallocation of funds previously used to compensate EU-15 farmers towards Green Box measures for the enlarged Union. For world prices 20% below 1994 levels, these costs are considerably higher at 16.6 bio ECU under option A, 10.5 bio ECU under option B and 20.0 bio ECU under option C.

Agricultural expenditure in terms of GNP varies from 6.5% to 13% of GNP (Slovak Republic and Poland respectively) under an extension of the current CAP, from 2% to 10% of GNP (Slovak Republic and Poland respectively) under the White Paper reform scenario, and from 11% to 18% of GNP (Slovak Republic and Hungary respectively) under the more comprehensive reform scenario.

Agricultural expenditure is therefore lower on average under the White Paper reform scenario. Clearly, under the present system these expenditures would be financed via the Community budget. However, one should also consider that under option A there is likely to be a pre-accession period where CEE countries would be expected to adjust their prices to those in the EU. The costs of such an operation would be extremely heavy for these countries (6.5 to 13% of GNP). Also, the level of expenditure estimated under option C assumes that all money previously spent on compensating EU farmers is now redirected to community-wide structural and modernization plans. Much of this money would now accrue to CEE countries. It is more likely that money spent on compensations would in part be withdrawn from the agricultural budget; this is because compensatory payments would constitute a one-off/short-term measure, beyond which expenditure would be expected to resume its normal path as dictated by the financial guidelines. Community expenditure under option C would therefore be in line with expenditure under option A.

Implications for the overall economy

As far as the rest of the economy is concerned, we know from models of agricultural trade that the presence of the CAP means higher agricultural production by 8 to 9%, but lower overall GNP growth by 0.5 to 4% (Goldin and Knudsen 1990; Nucifora 1995b). Our (partial equilibrium) model behaves along the same lines, suggesting that under option A, agricultural supply rises slightly and demand falls sharply; the sudden introduction of the price rise and the importance of food in the overall expenditure of the households would lead to a strong fall in demand for other sectors; as a result overall economic growth would certainly be slower.

Implications for income distribution

Although the budgetary costs of price support are generally considerable, the largest burden is still borne by the consumer. This burden is equivalent to an income-regressive tax on food. As we know, lower income people spend a higher proportion of their income on food (Engel's Law). Therefore, raising food prices has a more than proportional effect on the budget of poor people, hence the regressive nature of agricultural price support. Therefore, higher food prices generally raise inequality; however, this is not the case in those countries where the tax system takes into account and offsets the income-regressive nature of higher food prices.

This issue is particularly relevant to the CEE countries, as on average 36% of total household expenditures are devoted to food in these countries (Table 4). In Romania this figure is as high as 60%; once again, these are only average numbers. Thus, besides the increase in inequality induced by raising food prices, extending the high price level of the EU to these countries might have dangerous implications for the food security level of the poorest people in the CEECs.

Further, it is very difficult to orient price support to targeted groups; as a result farmers tend to benefit in proportion to the size of their production. Under option A the result is, therefore, a more uneven income distribution amongst both producers and consumers.

Social implications

The social implications of these reforms are difficult to predict and evaluate. It seems reasonable to expect farmers to leave rural areas unless they are paid compensation at a level which maintains their economic incentives to stay in the countryside. The experience of the EU, however, indicates that it is better to provide incentives for economic restructuring and diversification of rural areas than simply price support for agricultural production; this would induce farmers to earn a livelihood for themselves and to provide useful services to the community, rather than encouraging them to depend passively on public funds. Therefore, it appears that from a social point of view, our more comprehensive type of reform, which includes adequate funding for diversification of rural activities, is preferable.

International implications

International considerations are also important. Trade barriers and subsidization have distorted world markets and undermined developing countries' agriculture while contributing to the instability of commodity prices and adding a politically induced uncertainty in world markets. The internal protectionist policies of the EU and other developed countries have therefore had a strong impact on other countries' agriculture; this has often been a cause of tension in diplomatic and economic relations with these countries. More recently, with the Uruguay Round of GATT negotiation, there has been a clear move away from protectionist agricultural policies. It seems strange that CEECs countries should decide to increase their level of protectionism only to be forced to reduce it once again in a few years time when the GATT/WTO negotiations resume.

Environmental implications

The effects of either option A or B would be damaging to the environment. Higher prices would lead to increased intensity of cultivation, increased use of pesticides, and generally less environmentally friendly farming methods. It seems advisable to discourage western European methods of highly intensive farming in Eastern Europe. A set of policies such as those implemented under the more comprehensive reform scenario (Option C) would provide the right incentives to encourage farmers to preserve the environment directly and to avoid the desertion of rural areas by fostering alternative economic activities.

Future cuts in support prices, under option A, would have even stronger environmental implications because of the negative effects of the introduction of set-aside. The introduction of set-aside, however, ultimately depends on whether future compensatory payments will be fully decoupled.

6. Conclusions

Overall, offering CEECs farmers the same agricultural product prices as for EU farmers is therefore not highly desirable at present. In fact, CAP like policies would introduce substantial welfare losses and would increase income inequality. Further, these policies would have a negative impact on the agricultural sector of the CEECs.

It may be argued that in as far as the CEECs are concerned, the above mentioned distributional, efficiency and welfare costs of introducing price support policies ought to be weighted against the value of the financial transfers which would take place from the EU to the CEECs as a result of the extension of the CAP. Rough estimates of such transfers are provided from the levels agricultural expenditure/budgetary costs presented above. On average such transfers are in the region 5% of GNP under option B and 9% of GNP under options A and C. From our results, however, it is quite clear that the gains of such transfers are maximized when these transfers are received in the form of structural policies and policies for the modernization of the agri-food sector.

Under options B and C the price levels in the CEECs are not raised (except for products under quota in option B, i.e. milk), thus avoiding equity issues associated with higher food prices and welfare issues associated with price distortion. A transfer of resources still takes place, but this has the advantage of not penalizing the poor. Further, the efficiency of these direct transfers is now much higher. Almost none of the transfer is lost in welfare costs. Distributional benefits could be further increased under option C, by using at least part of the money not spent on price policies to support directly the income of poor farmers and to foster the agricultural development of particularly poor regions via suitable structural and modernization programs

Further, one should not forget that raising food prices is equivalent to imposing a tax on consumption to support the farmers. In the Common Agricultural Policy of the EU, only less than one third of all price support is accounted for by budgetary expenditure; the largest share of the costs is borne by the consumers; this cost implicitly falls on each individual country.

There are further implications of these policies. Since food expenditure in the CEECs occupies a high level of total consumers expenditure, the increase in food prices implied by the CAP may turn out to be equivalent to a prohibitive tax on disposable income. On the production side agricultural and food industries do not appear to be ready to respond dynamically to a sharp increase in incentives. Consequently, one could witness a situation where the sudden increase in agricultural prices could have a very negative impact on aggregate demand and, as a result, on the supply of non agricultural goods, while failing to have a positive impact on agricultural supply; overall this would lead to an increase in imports mainly from the EU. Effectively, something similar has already been happening in the past few years.

Further, these policies would hinder any improvement in the modernization and competitiveness of the agricultural sector and its upstream and downstream sectors by allowing inefficient firms to survive and to avoid adjustment. Besides obstructing a much needed rationalization of the food processing and distribution systems, and besides having a strong negative impact on domestic and particularly export demand for these products, such an increase in output prices is likely to translate into an increase in factor prices and land rents; this would further render the agricultural and agro-processing sectors less competitive on the world markets. The combined result of the above would work against the dynamic growth of CEECs agricultural sectors.

Thus, besides the economic, distributional and efficiency costs, it appears that the comprehensive effect of introducing agricultural market price support in the CEE countries, such as is envisaged in option A, would have a negative impact on the agricultural sector of these economies. It would reduce the sector's competitiveness, and it would directly hinder structural adjustment and modernization. The introduction of quotas, as under options A and B, also impedes the development of the sector and a fast adjustment of its structures. On the contrary a set of policies such as those envisaged in option C would accelerate the elimination of the inefficiencies present in the food processing and distribution systems, thus rendering the sector highly competitive on the world markets.

In conclusion, we know that the CAP is an expensive and inefficient policy which fails adequately to meet its many conflicting objectives. The external pressures of GATT and enlargement are certain to force policy adjustment within the next few years and the traditional approaches to the reform of the CAP cannot fully overcome these problems. Moreover they would seriously constrain, or discriminate against, CEECs' agriculture, preventing it from exploiting its potential comparative advantage. This study has shown that a reform involving the removal of production related support, cushioned by temporary, digressive fully decoupled compensation and slowly replaced by complementary environmental and socio-structural policies, would remove the serious distortions in EU agriculture, enable the Union to participate in the growth of world trade and allow social and regional objectives to be addressed directly. For the CEECs, such a reform would ease the path to accession, allow funds to be directed for modernization and restructuring and ultimately facilitate the emergence of dynamic agricultural sectors capable of making a major contribution to the economies of the CEECs and to an enlarged European Union.







1. We note that were the EU prices at the world level at the time of accession there would be no overproduction to justify set-aside being applied to CEC countries.

2. These measures are described in detail in Annex 2 of the GATT agreement of Marrakesh.

3. In the rest of the paper we refer to these countries as CEEC-5. Other countries also applying for membership are Bulgaria, Romania, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania (CEEC-10).

4. In this study key elasticities of demand and supply for Eastern Europe were drawn from compendia such as Sullivan et al (1992) and the work of the regional specialists at the USDA Economic Research Service, supplied personally. Where authoritative estimates of such parameters were unavailable, values were adopted from the databases for like agricultural economies elsewhere in Europe and Asia. These values were then modified for consistency with the patterns of production and expenditure in Eastern Europe.

5. This effect has not been proved true in the literature due to the early existence of agricultural protectionism in most countries, which has not given the chance to test for the impact of the introduction of agricultural support on productivity growth. Economic theory, however, tells us this is what we should expect; given the marginally higher returns to agriculture it can be expected the rates of return on research in the sector should also be higher, thus inducing extra research and innovation in that sector.

6. This is done by initially running a simulation where agricultural markets settle at prices 20% below 1994 levels; the results of this simulation provide the new reference scenario from which to analyze the policy changes.

7. For the EU there are substantial gains in consumer surplus as we move from the reference scenario to option B, and more in moving to option C. Likewise, producer surplus is dramatically reduced. It is worth emphasizing, however, that producer surplus does not reflect here the overall welfare impact for farmers; in particular, it neglects that vast sums of money have been redirected towards Green Box measures and does not reflect the potential value of these structural and environmental support measures to farm incomes.

8. For easy comparison, the whole CAP spending for 1992, 1993 and 1994 was 35.2, 38.4 and 39.5 bio ECU, respectively. The estimate of total budget costs of extending the present CAP to CEE countries presented in this study is in line with the various estimates which have been presented in the literature; these vary from as low as 3.7 bio ECU (Brenton and Gros 1993) to 40.5 bio ECU (Anderson and Tyers 1993b) (see in this respect the studies cited in Buckwell et al. (1995, p. 57) and Tarditi et al. (1995, p.38)). More recent estimates have concentrated in the 10-20 bio ECU range (Slater and Atkinson 1996; Munch 1996; EU Commission 1995).

The estimates provided in this study should, however, be taken with caution for the reasons below. Estimates of total budget and welfare costs are derived by assuming that the share of CAP expenditure on cereals, beef and milk (which are the products considered in the model) will stay the same as in 1994. However, the shift from price support to direct payments under the MacSharry reform has meant that the budgetary cost of support for cereals has increased more than proportionally in recent years; this leads to underestimate the total costs of the reform scenarios as expenditure on other products would now increase more than proportionally. Secondly, these shares are particularly inappropriate to estimate costs in CEE countries as they are not reflective of the composition of total agricultural output in those countries; this leads to overestimate total costs as the products covered in this study are marginally more important for CEECs than is the case for the EU-15. It follows that these estimates can be compared only approximately with estimates from other studies.

9. Ultimately this depends on the individual country's taxation policies.

References

Anderson, K. And Tyers, R. (1993a). More on welfare gains to developing countries. Journal of Agricultural Economics 44(2): 189-204.

Anderson, K. and Tyers, R. (1993b). Implications of EC Expansion for European Agricultural Policies, Trade and Welfare. Discussion Paper No.829. CEPR, London.

Brenton, P. and Gros, D. (1993). The budgetary implications of EC enlargement. CEP Working Paper Document No.78.

Buckwell, A.E. (1986). Controlling Surpluses by Area Reduction Programs. Discussion Paper in Agricultural Economics 86/2: 7-11. Wye College, Kent.

Buckwell, A.E., Haynes, J., Davidova, S. And Kwiecinski, A. (1995). Feasibility of an Agricultural Strategy to Prepare the Countries of Central and Eastern Europe for EU Accession. Study commissioned by the Directorate-General I of the European Commission. Brussels.

Commission of the European Community (1995). White Paper on Integrating the Central European Countries to the European Union. Official Documents. Brussels.

Csaki, C. (1995). Presidential Address. In: Peters, G.H. and Hedley, D. (eds.) (1995)Agricultural competitiveness: Market forces and policy choices. Proceedings of the Twenty-second International Conference of Agricultural Economists, held at Harare, Zimbabwe, 22-29 August 1994. Dartmouth, Aldershot.

Csaki, C. and Lerman, Z. (1994). Land Reform and Farm Sector Restructuring in the Former Socialist Countries of Europe. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 21 (3/4).

Goldin, I. and Knudsen, O. (eds.) (1990). Agricultural Trade Liberalization: Implications for Developing Countries. OECD, Paris/ World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Hartmann, M. (1996). Implications of Eastern Enlargement for the CAP. Paper presented at the 'CAP Reform: What Next?' conference held in Nottingham, March 1996.

Josling, T. (1993). The Reformed CAP and the Industrial World. Plenary Paper, VIIth EAAE Congress: 93-116. Stresa, Italy, September 6-10.

Münch, W. (1995). Possible Implications of an Accession of the Visegrad Countries to the EU. Agricultural Economics Society One-Day Conference on Integrating Central and Eastern Europe with the EU'. London, UK, 13 December 1995.

Nucifora, A.M.D. (1995a). Stato e tendenze dell'utilizzazione economica della terra nei paesi dell'Unione Europea. Rivista di Economia Agraria 50(2): 217-259.

Nucifora, AMD (1995b). The Economic Costs of the CAP: A Review of Quantitative Analyses. Consiglio Nazionale delle Ricerche, Progetto finalizzato RAISA. Quaderno per Discussione N.14. Università degli Studi di Siena, Dipartimento di Economia Politica.

OECD (ed) (1995). Agricultural Policies, Markets and Trade in the Central and Eastern European Countries, Selected New Independent States, Mongolia and China. OECD, Paris.

OECD (ed) (1994). Agricultural Policies, Markets and Trade in the Central and Eastern European Countries, Selected New Independent States, Mongolia and China. OECD, Paris.

Slater, J. and Atkinson, N. (1995). The Common Agricultural Policy and EU Enlargement to the East. Agricultural Economics Society One-Day Conference on 'Integrating Central and Eastern Europe with the EU'. London, UK, 13 December 1995.

Sullivan, R., Roningen, V., Leetma, S. and Grey, D. (1992). A Global Database for the Static World Policy Simulation (SWOPSIM) Modelling Framework. ERS. Staff Report No.AGES 9215. Washington, D.C., United States Department of Agriculture.

Tangermann, S. (1990). A Bond Scheme for Supporting Farm Incomes. In The Changing Role of the CAP (Marsh, J., Green, B., Kearney, B., Mahé, L., Tangermann, S., and Tarditi, S.). London, Belhaven Press: 93-101.

Tangermann, S. (1994). EC membership by the year 2000: a realistic objective? Agra Europe Conference 'Towards 2000: Agriculture, Agribusiness and the Food Industry in Central and Eastern Europe'. Budapest, Hungary, March 1994.

Tangermann, S., Josling, T. (1995). Pre-Accession Agricultural Policies for Central Europe and the European Union. Study commissioned by the Directorate-General I of the European Commission. Brussels.

Tarditi, S., Marsh, J., Senior-Nello, S. (1995). Agricultural Strategies for the Enlargement of the European Union to Central and Eastern European Countries. Study commissioned by the Directorate-General I of the European Commission. Brussels.

Tracy, M. (1995). The Commission's "Agricultural Strategy Paper": A Commentary. Agricultural Economics Society One-Day Conference on "Integrating Central and Eastern Europe with the EU". London, UK, 13 December 1995.

Tyers, R. (1994). Economic Reform in Eastern Europe and in the Former Soviet Union: Implications for International Food Markets. International Food Policy Research Institute. Research Report 99. Washington, D.C.

Wibberley, G. (1983). The Diversion of Land. in Agriculture: the Triumph and the Shame -An Independent Assessment, pp.17-34. Centre for Agricultural Strategy, University of Reading.

Table 1: Reference Scenario, Option A, Option B and Option C, at 1994 World Prices
Czech
Hungary
Poland
Slovak
Slovenia
EU-15
RoW
World
Czech
Hungary
Poland
Slovak
Slovenia
EU-15
RoW
World
unit Reference Scenario Option A
Handling margins: Cereals %31.6% 60.6%2.7% 49.0%86.2% 6.5%0.0% 0.0%28.0% 49.0%2.1% 45.9%85.3% 1.6%0.0% 0.0%
Handling margins: Beef %20.4% 49.7%39.6% 29.1%23.5% 22.9%0.0% 0.0%17.8% 46.7%29.4% 27.5%22.8% 3.5%0.0% 0.0%
Handling margins: Milk %22.0% 10.2%49.5% 20.6%25.0% 9.2%0.0% 0.0%19.9% 9.6%35.7% 20.1%24.6% 2.0%0.0% 0.0%
Average Border Protection Rate %3.4% 17.4%-27.9% 3.4%52.6% 40.4%0.0% 0.0%33.6% 26.7%43.7% 27.7%71.4% 42.5%0.0% 0.0%
Price Distorting Support Expenditure (MioEcu)66.2 269.570.7 17.611.0 5158.70.0 0.0626.1 668.13079.5 237.258.7 2923.9-0.0 0.0
Producer Surplus(MioEcu) -207.3-260.8 -1683.0-120.1 110.427769.8 -7940.7-9775.1 875.6824.4 2707.9340.3 127.628294.0 -16080.3-20279.4
Consumer Surplus(MioEcu) 170.1219.3 1222.7110.3 -151.0-28879.6 7872.29775.1 -580.3-605.7 -1397.1-243.9 -141.6-28879.7 16235.920279.4
Economic Welfare Impact (MioEcu)-103.4 -311.0-531.0 -27.4-51.6 -6268.6-68.5 0.0-330.8 -449.3-1768.7 -140.8-72.7 -3509.6155.6 0.0
CAP-wide Economic Welfare Impact (MioEcu)-257.0 -773.1-1320.0 -68.0-128.2 -15581.8 -822.3 -1116.9-4396.5 -349.9-180.8 -8723.8
Total budget expenditure (MioEcu)142.1 360.51800.2 238.234.5 15897.40.0 0.0806.6 841.83906.2 309.482.1 27644.60.0 0.0
CAP-wide Total Budget Expenditure (MioEcu)353.3 896.24474.8 592.185.7 39516.2 2005.0 2092.49709.8 769.2204.2 68716.4
CAP Expenditure as a % of 1993 GNP %1.3% 2.8%6.1% 6.8%0.9% 0.7% 7.5%6.4% 13.2%8.8% 2.1%1.2%
Welfare Costs as a % of 1993 GNP %-0.4% -1.0%-0.7% -0.3%-0.5% -0.3% -1.2% -1.4%-2.4% -1.6%-0.7% -0.1%
Cost of Transferring 1 ECU to Farmers 1.7 1.91.3 1.12.5 1.4 1.41.5 1.51.5 1.91.1
Czech
Hungary
Poland
Slovak
Slovenia
EU-15
RoW
World
Czech
Hungary
Poland
Slovak
Slovenia
EU-15
RoW
World
unit Option B Option C
Handling margins: Cereals %28.2% 49.9%2.1% 46.1%85.3% 1.7%0.0% 0.0%5.6% 6.1%0.2% 11.4%63.9% 0.0%0.0% 0.0%
Handling margins: Beef %18.2% 47.2%30.7% 27.8%22.9% 3.7%0.0% 0.0%6.6% 27.0%6.9% 16.0%16.8% 0.3%0.0% 0.0%
Handling margins: Milk %19.8% 9.5%35.3% 20.1%24.6% 1.9%0.0% 0.0%5.0% 3.4%3.5% 10.8%16.1% 0.0%0.0% 0.0%
Average Border Protection Rate %33.4% 7.4%24.7% 39.4%52.5% 24.6%-0.0% 0.0%-1.9% -2.0%0.0% -3.8%21.3% 0.0%0.0% -0.0%
Price Distorting Support Expenditure (MioEcu)338.8 137.02404.1 64.286.0 2441.0-0.0 0.036.6 64.989.7 50.641.7 15.00.0 0.0
Producer Surplus(MioEcu) 369.5214.2 1440.691.5 64.313397.7 -8860.5-12256.1 -18.6-20.2 -57.9-8.4 -2.5-540.8 -2957.5-3607.0
Consumer Surplus(MioEcu) -222.1-207.8 -501.1-88.3 -52.0-12858.0 9149.512256.1 13.714.3 40.86.0 3.1604.1 2924.23607.0
Economic Welfare Impact (MioEcu)-191.4 -130.5-1464.7 -61.0-73.7 -1901.3289.0 -0.0-41.5 -70.8-106.8 -53.0-41.1 48.3-33.3 0.0
CAP-wide Economic Welfare Impact (MioEcu)-475.8 -324.3-3640.8 -151.6-183.3 -4726.0 -103.2 -176.1-265.4 -131.7-102.1 120.0
Total budget expenditure (MioEcu)477.7 246.22923.9 113.6110.5 26939.90.0 0.01204.8 1436.03393.8 641.7194.5 31124.50.0 0.0
CAP-wide Total Budget Expenditure (MioEcu)1187.4 611.97267.9 282.4274.6 66964.7 2994.8 3569.48436.1 1595.1483.5 77366.3
CAP Expenditure as a % of 1993 GNP %4.4% 1.9%9.9% 3.2%2.8% 1.1% 11.2% 11.0%11.5% 18.3%4.9% 1.3%
Welfare Costs as a % of 1993 GNP %-0.7% -0.4%-2.0% -0.7%-0.8% -0.0% -0.2% -0.2%-0.1% -0.6%-0.4% 0.0%
Cost of Transferring 1 ECU to Farmers 1.4 1.51.5 1.51.7 1.1 1.01.0 1.01.1 1.21.0


Table 2: Reference Scenario, Option A, Option B and Option C, at Prices 20% below 1994 World Prices
Czech
Hungary
Poland
Slovak
Slovenia
EU-15
RoW
World
Czech
Hungary
Poland
Slovak
Slovenia
EU-15
RoW
World
unit Reference Scenario Option A
Handling margins: Cereals %31.3% 60.0%12.0% 49.1%132.7% 6.3%0.0% 0.0%27.7% 48.4%9.3% 45.9%131.4% 1.5%0.0% 0.0%
Handling margins: Beef %20.1% 37.0%24.5% 29.9%54.4% 23.1%0.0% 0.0%17.2% 34.6%17.7% 28.0%52.7% 3.5%0.0% 0.0%
Handling margins: Milk %22.9% 12.7%36.7% 0.5%17.9% 9.3%0.0% 0.0%20.7% 11.9%26.4% 0.5%17.6% 2.0%0.0% 0.0%
Average Border Protection Rate %18.3% 33.3%-15.3% 16.9%91.0% 66.8%0.0% 0.0%61.7% 54.8%74.1% 55.6%114.8% 70.4%-0.0% 0.0%
Price Distorting Support Expenditure (MioEcu)77.1 274.6338.9 21.012.3 5842.20.0 0.0808.0 761.73308.9 294.681.3 4457.20.0 0.0
Producer Surplus(MioEcu) 122.073.1 -597.615.0 156.938179.5 -10809.1 -13192.91229.9 1177.23752.2 482.7178.8 39141.4-17942.8 -22312.0
Consumer Surplus(MioEcu) -113.0-84.9 379.0-14.3 -213.6-41018.1 10617.713192.9 -863.3-907.8 -2238.4-368.2 -204.0-41018.2 17949.922312.1
Economic Welfare Impact (MioEcu)-68.1 -286.3-557.5 -20.3-69.0 -8680.8-191.4 0.0-441.3 -492.4-1795.2 -180.1-106.5 -6334.07.2 0.1
CAP-wide Economic Welfare Impact (MioEcu)-169.2 -711.7-1385.9 -50.5-171.5 -21578.0 -1097.1 -1223.9-4462.3 -447.7-264.8 -15744.4
Total budget expenditure (MioEcu)173.8 365.52081.8 241.844.0 16689.00.0 0.01013.4 948.14250.4 375.4108.3 29610.80.0 0.0
CAP-wide Total Budget Expenditure (MioEcu)432.1 908.45174.7 601.1109.3 41484.10.0 0.02518.9 2356.710565.4 933.0269.3 73603.90.0 0.0
CAP Expenditure as a % of 1993 GNP %1.6% 2.8%7.1% 6.9%1.1% 0.7% 9.4% 7.3%14.4% 10.7%2.7% 1.2%
Welfare Costs as a % of 1993 GNP %-0.3% -0.9%-0.8% -0.2%-0.7% -0.4% -1.7% -1.5%-2.4% -2.1%-1.1% -0.3%
Cost of Transferring 1 ECU to Farmers 1.4 1.81.3 1.12.6 1.5 1.4 1.51.4 1.52.0 1.2
Czech
Hungary
Poland
Slovak
Slovenia
EU-15
RoW
World
Czech
Hungary
Poland
Slovak
Slovenia
EU-15
RoW
World
unit Option B Option C
Handling margins: Cereals %27.9% 49.8%9.3% 46.2%131.3% 1.7%0.0% 0.0%5.4% 5.6%0.9% 10.3%96.0% 0.0%0.0% 0.0%
Handling margins: Beef %17.9% 35.2%18.9% 28.5%53.1% 3.7%0.0% 0.0%6.3% 19.9%4.1% 16.0%38.6% 0.3%0.0% 0.0%
Handling margins: Milk %20.6% 11.8%25.9% 0.5%17.6% 1.9%0.0% 0.0%5.2% 4.2%2.5% 0.3%11.6% 0.0%0.0% 0.0%
Average Border Protection Rate %49.2% 56.5%43.0% 55.3%83.6% 40.4%-0.0% 0.0%-1.8% -1.9%0.3% -3.4%32.0% 0.0%0.0% 0.0%
Price Distorting Support Expenditure (MioEcu)445.3 113.02613.3 75.1121.2 4206.1-0.0 0.024.1 42.235.4 36.955.3 18.7-0.0 0.0
Producer Surplus(MioEcu) 512.4299.3 1962.1126.8 88.518454.4 -10251.8 -13933.2-15.6 -17.9-47.1 -7.8-2.1 -436.4-2820.4 -3349.1
Consumer Surplus(MioEcu) -308.9-283.9 -779.3-123.1 -71.4-17526.3 10531.513933.2 12.813.5 39.05.7 2.9541.4 2731.93349.1
Economic Welfare Impact (MioEcu)-241.8 -97.6-1430.5 -71.4-104.1 -3278.0279.7 -0.0-26.9 -46.6-43.5 -39.0-54.5 86.3-88.5 0.0
CAP-wide Economic Welfare Impact (MioEcu)-601.1 -242.6-3555.7 -177.6-258.8 -8148.1 -66.8 -115.8-108.2 -97.0-135.4 214.6
Total budget expenditure (MioEcu)595.2 217.83157.0 125.7149.6 29073.00.0 0.01230.4 1497.33659.3 686.6215.1 30787.20.0 0.0
CAP-wide Total Budget Expenditure (MioEcu)1479.5 541.57847.3 312.4372.0 72266.90.0 0.03058.4 3721.89096.0 1706.8534.7 76527.90.0 0.0
CAP Expenditure as a % of 1993 GNP %5.5% 1.7%10.7% 3.6%3.8% 1.2% 11.5% 11.5%12.4% 19.6%5.5% 1.3%
Welfare Costs as a % of 1993 GNP %-0.91% -0.30%-1.95% -0.82%-1.06% -0.14% -0.10% -0.14%-0.06% -0.45%-0.56% 0.00%
Cost of Transferring 1 ECU to Farmers 1.4 1.41.5 1.61.7 1.1 1.0 1.01.0 1.11.3 1.0

Table 3: Agricultural Producer Prices in CEE Countries Relative to the Respective Prices in the EU-15 (1994)
Wheat
Milk
Beef
Pork
Poultry
Czech Republic
66
54
59
94
68
Hungary
56
70
52
98
77
Poland
73
33
40
103
88
Slovak Republic
63
52
50
88
74
Slovenia
131
74
32
92
64
Romania
60
57
Bulgaria
40
36
24
53
44
Lithuania
45
21
22
81
Latvia
90
26
18
77
Estonia
56
26
12
43
EU-15
100
100
100
100
100
Source: Own calculations based on European Commission (ed.) (1995) Agricultural Situation and Prospects in the Central and Eastern European Countries. Summary Report. Brussels.
Table 4: Food Expenditure as % of Total Household Expenditure
Population
Food Expenditure
in Mio
as % of Total Household Expenditure
Czech Republic
10.3
32
Hungary
10.3
31
Poland
38.5
30
Slovak Republic
5.3
28
Slovenia
1.9
28
CEEC-5
66.4
31
Romania
22.7
60
Bulgaria
8.5
48
Lithuania
3.8
58
Latvia
2.6
45
Estonia
1.6
39
CEEC-10
105.5
36
EU-15
369.7
22
Source: Hartmann, 1996