STUDYING POLICY DELIVERY SYSTEMS
Dr. Frances Sandiford and Dr.
Ed Rossmiller
Rome, Italy
This summary is based on a paper
presented at the Agricultural Economics Society Conference, University
of Newcastle-upon-Tyne, 27-30 March 1996. It reflects only part
of the original text as time constraints as well as the particular
interests of the audience necessitated a sharper and different
focus on the paper's policy implementation aspects.
Agricultural policy implementation:
the policy delivery system
There has been much discussion about
the new agricultural policies that the CEECs need to introduce
as part of their move towards market economies, and perhaps also
with a view to membership of the EU or a regional trading block.
In contrast, no systematic attention has been given by policy
advisers to the question of policy implementation, given that
many of the institutions, linkages and rules that formerly constituted
the implementation process have been dismantled or disrupted.
Our paper is concerned with agricultural policy implementation,
as distinct from policy analysis, policy advice or policy making.
The unit for studying agricultural policy implementation is the policy delivery system, which we define as being the total modality of implementing a given policy. The first question to be addressed is what constitutes an agricultural policy delivery system. Our definition includes the unique set of institutions, individuals, processes and rules that together deliver the benefits of the policy to a target group and enable control to be exercised to ensure adherence to the rules of access.
As such, policy delivery systems are
almost infinitely variable. Consider a couple of examples. Assume
a policy objective of increasing farm incomes, and that the instrument
selected is an import tax. The policy delivery system consists
of border controls and tax collection, and the domestic market,
which acts as the mechanism for transmitting the price effect
to the farm gate. The extent to which the policy delivery system
succeeds in achieving the policy objective will depend, amongst
other things, on the extent to which the border controls are policed
and the degree of price transmission by the market to the price
received by farmers.
Now assume the same objective of increasing
farm incomes but through the provision of technical advice to
improve agricultural productivity. This could be provided through
a government extension agency, or by in-house technical experts
(as was common on the large state and collective farms), or through
commercial organizations or public institutions such as universities.
The government could fund the advice in whole or in part, or
not at all, but it does not have to deliver the service itself.
The way in which the service is provided to achieve defined policy
objectives constitutes the delivery system for that policy.
Our understanding of policy delivery
systems therefore encompasses all types of agricultural policies
be they pricing policies or service provision, whether they involve
public goods, private goods, or something in between. By looking
at policy implementation as a delivery system,
we are able to cope with the complexity and sheer diversity of
agricultural policy implementation schemes.
Studying policy delivery systems:
the structure-conduct-performance paradigm
We are suggesting a framework
for structured thinking about policy delivery systems
that can assist those involved in policy implementation in making
their advice or decisions more relevant, workable and reliable.
In order to structure our thinking about policy delivery systems,
we take as our point of departure some of the ideas from the structure-conduct-performance
approach to analyzing markets developed since the 1930s in the
industrial organization literature. At its simplest, the market
structure-conduct-performance paradigm attempts to evaluate market
performance in the form of output and prices in relation
to firms' conduct (behaviour) and the market structure
of the industry (which are themselves inter-related). Adaptation
of the paradigm from a market focus to the analysis of policy
delivery systems necessitates a rethinking of the concepts of
structure, conduct and performance; we also introduce an exogenous
reference point: the policy objective. Our framework
must therefore allow for the definition of policy objectives,
a description of system structure, an analysis of system conduct,
and an assessment of the system's performance.
Defining policy objectives
The first stage in using the structure-conduct-performance
framework to study a particular policy delivery system is to obtain
a working and workable definition of the policy objective, and
to obtain the government's agreement to that definition.
Defining the policy objective is not a one-off act; rather it
is an iterative and interactive process. The definition needs
to be questioned throughout the analysis. If something does not
fit, we need to think about it and retrace our steps - again
and again if necessary.
Describing structure
The structure
component of the analysis focuses on the system through which
the policy is implemented to transfer the benefits from wheresoever
they derive to the hands of the targeted recipients. It is both
a description of the policy delivery system - institutions,
instruments and processes - and an analysis of the functions
that are apparently intended to be performed at each point
and by each component of the system. We say "apparently
intended" because one must take a skeptical approach given
the potential for hidden agendas and private interests in the
working of the system. The structure component of the analysis
is heavily descriptive and should reflect the system as it is
apparently intended to be, and to operate. On the basis of the
findings, a flow diagram can be prepared.
Analyzing conduct
The conduct (or behaviour) component
of the analysis covers how the institutions and individuals in
the system operate to ensure and monitor compliance and effect
delivery of the benefits to the targeted recipients. Or how they
might be operating, given the opportunities, pressures and constraints,
to deliver outcomes that are inconsistent with the original objectives
of the policy. This is an analysis of the way the system works
in practice - the actual as opposed to intended functions
performed, where and how private or extraneous interests and activities
affect the way the system works.
The conduct component is strongly
investigative and analytical. It covers the same points as the
structure component, but from a different standpoint. The aim
is to lay out how the system really works as opposed to how it
is apparently intended to work - to pinpoint where in the
system and how, with what consequences for outcomes, actual conduct
or behaviour affects system operation. On the basis of the findings
of the conduct component, a modified flow diagram can be prepared
to illustrate how and where the apparent intentions and the real
world diverge.
Assessing performance
Finally, the performance component
of the analysis is an assessment of how well the policy delivery
system meets the original objective of the policy in terms of
delivering the scheduled benefits to the targeted recipients.
We propose four criteria for this assessment of performance:
effectiveness, efficiency, enforceability, and equity, each of
which is elaborated below. A note of caution: these criteria
are not tidy categories of mutual exclusivity; they overlap and
interact. The points that need to be examined under each heading
will differ from case to case, as will the relative importance
of each criterion.
¨
Effectiveness:
Doing the right thing. This is the
top-level criterion in that it is the overall measure of whether
the policy objective is being achieved, which is why agreement
about the policy objective is so vital. Effectiveness means that
the system operates in such a way as to be successful in producing
the desired result, i.e., it is capable of delivering the intended
benefits to the targeted recipients and, indeed, does so. A necessary,
but not sufficient, condition for effectiveness is that the system
is capable of delivery. To be fully effective, the system must
actually deliver. The other three performance criteria -
efficiency, enforceability and equity - are second-level
criteria that jointly contribute to overall effectiveness.
¨¨
Efficiency:
Doing the thing right. This criterion
looks at the cost of delivering the policy to the targeted recipients.
It is contingent upon effectiveness: what if the system spends
the benefits but the targeted beneficiaries do not receive them?
In this construct, efficiency has no real meaning if effectiveness
is not fulfilled. In other words, does it mean anything if the
wrong thing is done right?
¨¨
Enforceability:
The ability to make sure that the
benefits reach the targeted beneficiaries, non-complying or unintended
beneficiaries are excluded, and that benefits are not creamed
off by intermediaries. Enforceability is not the same as enforcement,
but is a pre-condition for it. Given enforceability, non-enforcement
can take place for a number of reasons.
¨¨
Equity:
Ensuring consistent and impartial
access under the rules to the benefits across the targeted recipients.
Again, equity must be seen in the context of the objective of
the policy itself. Equity is the assurance of equal opportunity
to access to the benefits under the rules. If the potential beneficiary
qualifies under the rules of the game access to the benefits is
assured, if not, access is denied.
This interpretation of equity is concerned
with the impartiality and consistency of the policy deliverer.
From the point of view of the intended beneficiary, there is
another equity consideration: the costs of access.
Assessing performance is obviously
a complicated process, and will produce a great deal of information
that needs to be assimilated purposively. We therefore need to
be quite clear about what we want the process to lead to. This
depends on the reason for the study being undertaken in the first
place. One of the following three is probable:
×
There are grounds for believing that the effectiveness of the
system is inadequate, and what is required are recommendations
for improving the working of the system, assuming that we find
it to be capable of improvement, or for setting up an alternative
system.
×
The government wishes to change the policy instruments for reasons
unconnected with the effectiveness of the delivery system, e.g.,
to comply with GATT/WTO commitments or to reduce the costs of
the policy itself, and wants to know if an existing policy delivery
system can be used.
×
For ideological or budgetary reasons, changes to an existing policy
delivery system are under consideration, e.g., the privatization
of a parastatal marketing organization or a reduction in the number
of public sector personnel who provide extension services.
Any of these reasons could be applicable in the CEECs. The extensive structural and institutional changes in the agricultural sectors of the transition economies - not just as result of agricultural policies - have caused serious problems for agricultural policy implementation. We have proposed a way of looking at the question systematically with a view to improving the performance of existing policy delivery systems, and to designing alternative systems.